Categories
When business decision-makers look at conjoint and discrete choice model output, how should the share results be interpreted and used? In this post, we share our thoughts about preference share and market share, based on decades of practical experience.
If you used a conjoint-based (or discrete choice) simulation model and saw the following output:
you might assume the figures represent market shares. But, the output of a conjoint simulation model is known as a “share of preference.” In this post, we will discuss the important differences between preference share and market share, and provide our thoughts about how to interpret and use these figures to help with business decisions.
In previous posts, we have described the basics of conjoint analysis and simulation modeling. In this post, we pick up at the point of using output. [But, if you don’t have time to read the prior posts, work with this: A conjoint model compares respondent preferences for the building blocks of a decision – such as which TV to buy – with the offerings in the market. The output predicts the level of preference any product might achieve.]
Most model users might prefer to simplify and assume that preference share equals market share. That would seem to make life—and revenue projections—easy. But, conjoint and discrete choice simulation models are based on important assumptions, some of which are basic to market research (e.g., representative sample, accurate answers, stated preferences will translate into behavior) and others which are unique to conjoint: All products have equal levels of distribution; Consumers are fully aware of and understand the specifications of all products; All products have reached their equilibrium shares (that is, full adoption has occurred); All relevant attributes that contribute to share have been included.
What’s a Researcher To Do? Take a close look at share of preference AND market share.
So far, this post may seem focused on caveats. Let’s switch gears. The good news: Shares of preference are very powerful. They help us understand what a product’s potential is, how well-liked it is versus competitive products, and what aspects of the product (such as brand, a particular feature, or a competitive price) are most contributing to preference. In addition, by simulating changes to the product (such as changing the mix of features, or raising or lowering price), we can determine the relative benefit of our strategic options. We can see which changes most increase or decrease preference, and which have only slight impacts.
But, the inevitable question arises: Why don’t these shares look like our market shares? Skittish researchers will apply external effects, which are simply multipliers that can make preference shares look like market shares. In our experience, applying external effects robs the business decision-maker of valuable information. We recommend comparing preference shares to market shares. Why? Because there is information hiding there!
If our product has a preference share that is lower than its known market share, what might be going on? Let’s start by realizing this suggests that the product is selling at a higher level than “preference” would indicate it should be. Possible underlying causes:
If our product has a preference share that is higher than its known market share, what might be happening? Start by realizing that our product is not selling up to its potential. Possible underlying causes:
When preference share does not equal market share, the conjoint model won’t necessarily tell you whether distribution, awareness, loyalty, or inertia are at work. But, you will have important information about whether your product is in a vulnerable position (preference is less than market share) or whether you have an opportunity (preference is greater than market share), even before any product or price changes are made.
What Else Can Be Done? Look at conjoint share results over time.
As noted above, time can be a factor in modeling… the conjoint model assumes equilibrium shares have been achieved. To see how time may figure into the equation, two approaches can be used:
Bottom Line: Use the power of shares produced by conjoint analysis.
Instead of approaching preference shares with trepidation (“will they look like market shares?”), we suggest conducting a thorough and open exploration into the differences between preference and market shares. There’s information that can lead the way to vital understandings and profitable strategies.
-June 2010
This content was provided by Sawtooth Technologies. Visit their website at www.sawtooth.com.
Sign Up for
Updates
Get content that matters, written by top insights industry experts, delivered right to your inbox.
67k+ subscribers